Saturday, September 25, 2010

Why Is Paul Krugman Blaming Foreigners for the Financial Crisis?

http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2010/09/20/why_is_paul_krugman_blaming_foreigners_for_the_financial_crisis?page=0,0

Two years after the collapse of Lehman Brothers, economists are still debating the causes of and villains behind the 2008 financial crisis, whose ongoing fallout can be seen in the weak recovery and stagnant job market that continues to bedevil U.S. President Barack Obama and his economic advisors. In a recent article in the New York Review of Books, Paul Krugman and Robin Wells lay down another marker in this debate, while caricaturing my recent book, Fault Lines, in the process.



The article says a lot about the policy views of Krugman (for simplicity, I will say "Krugman" and "he" instead of "Krugman and Wells" and "they"), with whom I have disagreed in the past. Rather than focus on the innuendo about my motives and beliefs in the review, let me focus instead on differences of substance.
First, Krugman starts with a diatribe on why so many economists are "asking how we got into this mess rather than telling us how to get out of it." Krugman apparently believes that his standard response of more stimulus applies regardless of the reasons why we are in the economic downturn. Yet it is precisely because I think the policy response to the last crisis contributed to getting us into this one that it is worthwhile examining how we got into this mess, and to resist the unreflective policies that Krugman advocates.
My book emphasizes a number of related issues that led to our current predicament.
Krugman discusses and dismisses two -- the political push for easy housing credit in the United States and overly lax monetary policy in the years 2002-2005 -- while favoring a third, global trade imbalances (which he does not acknowledge are a central theme in my book). Focusing exclusively on the imbalances as Krugman does, while ignoring why the United States became a deficit country, gives us a grossly incomplete understanding of what happened. Finally, Krugman ignores an important factor I emphasize -- the incentives of bankers and their willingness to seek out and take the wild risks that brought the system down.
Let's start with the political push to expand housing credit. I argue that in an attempt to offset the consequences of rising income inequality, politicians on both sides of the aisle pushed easy housing credit through government units like the Federal Housing Administration, and by imposing increasingly rigorous mandates on government sponsored enterprises (GSEs) such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Interestingly, Krugman neither disputes my characterization of the incentives of politicians nor the detailed documentation of government initiatives and mandates calling for easy credit for the poor. What he disputes vehemently is whether government policy contributed to the housing bubble, and in particular, whether Fannie and Freddie were partly responsible.
In absolving Fannie and Freddie, Krugman has been consistent over time, though his explanations as to why Fannie and Freddie are not partially to blame have morphed as his errors have been pointed out. First, he argued that Fannie and Freddie could not participate in sub-prime financing. Then he insisted that their share of financing was falling in the years mortgage loan quality deteriorated the most. Now he claims that if they indeed did acquire substantial amounts of sub-prime exposure (and he says they did not), it was because of the profit motive and not to fulfill a social objective.
In a July 14, 2008 op-ed in the New York Times, Krugman explained why Fannie and Freddie were blameless. "Partly that's because regulators, responding to accounting scandals at the companies, placed temporary restraints on both Fannie and Freddie that curtailed their lending just as housing prices were really taking off," he wrote. "Also, they didn't do any subprime lending, because they can't: the definition of a subprime loan is precisely a loan that doesn't meet the requirement, imposed by law, that Fannie and Freddie buy only mortgages issued to borrowers who made substantial down payments and carefully documented their income. So whatever bad incentives the implicit federal guarantee creates have been offset by the fact that Fannie and Freddie were and are tightly regulated with regard to the risks they can take. You could say that the Fannie-Freddie experience shows that regulation works." [emphasis mine]
Critics were quick to point out that Krugman had his facts wrong. As Charles Calomiris, a professor at Columbia University, and Peter Wallison of the American Enterprise Institute (and member of the financial crisis inquiry commission) explained, "Here Krugman demonstrates confusion about the law (which did not prohibit subprime lending by the GSEs), misunderstands the regulatory regime under which they operated (which did not have the capacity to control their risk-taking), and mismeasures their actual subprime exposures (which he wrongly states were zero)."
So Krugman shifted his emphasis. In his blog critique of a Financial Times op-ed I wrote in June 2010, Krugman no longer argued that Fannie and Freddie could not buy sub-prime mortgages. Instead, he emphasized the slightly falling share of Fannie and Freddie's residential mortgage securitizations in the years 2004 to 2006 as the reason they were not responsible. Here again he presents a misleading picture. Not only did Fannie and Freddie purchase whole sub-prime loans that were not securitized (and are thus not counted in its share of securitizations), they also bought substantial amounts of private-label mortgage backed securities issued by others. When these are taken into account, Fannie and Freddie's share of the sub-prime market financing did increase even in those years.
Of course, one could question this form of analysis. Asset prices and bubbles have momentum. Even if Fannie and Freddie had simply ignited the process, and not fueled it in the go-go years of 2004-2006, they would bear some responsibility. Krugman never considers this possibility.
In the current review piece, Krugman first quotes the book by Nouriel Roubini and Stephen Mihm: "The huge growth in the subprime market was primarily underwritten not by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac but by private mortgage lenders like Countrywide. Moreover, the Community Reinvestment Act long predates the housing bubble.... Overblown claims that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac single-handedly caused the subprime crisis are just plain wrong."
Clearly, Fannie and Freddie did not originate sub-prime mortgages directly -- they are not equipped to do so. But they fuelled the boom by buying or guaranteeing them. Indeed, Countrywide was one of the GSEs' largest originators of sub-prime mortgages, according to work by Ed Pinto, a former chief credit officer of Fannie Mae, and participated from very early on in Fannie Mae's drive into affordable housing.
Consider, for instance, this press release from 1992:
Countrywide Funding Corporation and the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae) announced today that they have signed a record commitment to finance $8 billion in home mortgages. Fannie Mae said the agreement is the single largest commitment in its history.… The $8 billion agreement includes a previously announced $1.25 billion of a variety of Fannie Mae's affordable home mortgages, including reduced down payment loans....
"We are delighted to participate in this historic event, and we are particularly proud that a substantial portion of the $8 billion commitment will directly benefit lower income Americans," said Countrywide President Angelo Mozilo.… "We look forward to the rapid fulfillment of this commitment so that Countrywide can sign another record-breaking agreement with Fannie Mae," Mozilo said.
Of course, as Fannie and Freddie bought the garbage loans that lenders like Countrywide originated, they helped fuel the decline in lending standards. Also, while the Community Reinvestment Act was enacted in 1979, it was the more vigorous enforcement of the provisions of the act in the early 1990s that gave the government a lever to push its low-income lending objectives, a fact the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) once boasted about (see here and here). If the government itself took credit for its successes in expanding home ownership, why is Krugman not willing to accept its contribution to the subsequent bust as too many lower middle-class families ended up in homes they could not afford? I agree there is room for legitimate differences of opinion on the quality of data, and the extent of government responsibility, but to argue that the government had no role in directing credit, or in the subsequent bust, is simply ideological myopia.
Perhaps more interesting is that after citing Roubini and Mihm, Krugman repeats his earlier claim; "As others have pointed out, Fannie and Freddie actually accounted for a sharply reduced share of the home lending market as a whole during the peak years of the bubble." Now, however, he attributes the inaccurate claim that Fannie and Freddie accounted for a sharply reduced share of the home-lending market to nameless "others." But that is just the prelude to changing his story once again: "To the extent that they did purchase dubious home loans, they were in pursuit of profit, not social objectives -- in effect, they were trying to catch up with private lenders." In other words, if they did do it (and he denies they did), it was because of the profit motive.
Clearly, everything Fannie and Freddie did was because of the profit motive -- after all, they were private corporations. But I don't know how we can tell without more careful examination how much of the lending they did was to meet government affordable-housing mandates or to curry favor with Congress in order to preserve their profitable prime-mortgage franchise, and how much was to increase the bottom line immediately. Perhaps Krugman can tell us how he determined their intent?
Let me move on to Krugman's second criticism of my diagnosis of the crisis. He argues that the U.S. Federal Reserve's very accommodative monetary policy over the period 2003 to 2005 was also not responsible for the crisis. Here, Krugman is characteristically dismissive of alternative views. In his review, he says that there were good reasons for the Fed to keep rates low given the high unemployment rate. Although this may be a justification for the Fed's policy (as I argue in my book, it was precisely because the Fed was focused on a stubbornly high unemployment rate that it took its eye off the irrational exuberance building in housing markets and the financial sector), it in no way validates the claim that the policy did not contribute to the manic lending or housing bubble.
A second argument Krugman makes is that Europe, too, had bubbles; the European Central Bank (ECB), meanwhile, was less aggressive than the Fed, so monetary policy could not be responsible. It is true that the European Central Bank was less aggressive, but only slightly so; it brought its key refinancing rate down to only 2 percent while the Fed brought the Fed Funds rate down to 1 percent. Clearly, both rates were low by historical standards. More important, what Krugman does not point out is that different European economies had differing inflation rates, so the real monetary policy rate (that is, the difference between the nominal rate and inflation, reflecting the return investors get in purchasing power, which is what they care about) was substantially different across the Eurozone despite a common nominal policy rate. Countries that had strongly negative real policy rates -- Ireland and Spain are primary exhibits -- had a housing boom and bust, while countries like Germany with low inflation, and therefore higher real policy rates, did not. Indeed, a working paper by two ECB economists, Angela Maddaloni and José-Luis Peydró, indicates that the ultra-low rates by both the ECB and the Fed at this time had a strong causal effect in relaxing banks' commercial, mortgage, and retail lending standards over this period.
I admit that there is much less consensus on whether the Fed helped create the housing bubble and the banking crisis than on whether Fannie and Freddie were involved. Ben Bernanke, a monetary economist of the highest caliber, denies it, while John Taylor, an equally respected monetary economist, insists on it.
Krugman, of course, has an interest in defending the Fed and criticizing alternative viewpoints. He himself advocated the policies the Fed followed, and in fact, was critical of the Fed raising rates even when it belatedly did so in 2004. Then, as he does now, Krugman emphasized the dangers of a Japanese-style deflation, as well as the slow progress in bringing back jobs. Then, as he does now, he advocated more stimulus. Then, as he does now, Krugman ignored the adverse long-term consequences of the policies he advocated.
Finally, if he denies a role for government housing policies or for monetary policy, or even warped banker incentives, then to what does Krugman attribute the crisis? His answer is over-saving foreigners. In short, countries with trade surpluses, such as Germany and China, had to reinvest their resulting financial windfalls in the United States, pushing down U.S. long-term interest rates in the process, and igniting a housing bubble that eventually burst and led to the financial panic. But this is only a partial explanation, as I argue in my book. The United States did not have to run a large trade deficit and absorb the capital inflows -- the claim that it did sounds very much like that of the over-indulgent and over-indebted rake who blames his creditors for being willing to finance him. U.S. policies encouraged over-consumption and over-borrowing, and unless we understand where these policies came from, we have no hope of addressing the causes of this crisis. Unfortunately, these are the policies that Krugman wants to push again. This is precisely why we have to understand the history of how we got here, and why Krugman wants nothing to do with that enterprise.
There is also a matter of detail suggesting why we cannot only blame the foreigners. The housing bubble, as Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider of Stanford University have argued, was focused in the lower-income segments of the market, unlike in the typical U.S. housing boom. Why did foreign money gravitate to the low income segment of the housing market? Why did past episodes when the U.S. ran large current account deficits not result in similar housing booms and busts? Could the explanation lie in U.S. policies?
Many people -- bankers, regulators, governments, households, and economists among others -- share the blame for the crisis. Because there are so many, the blame game is not useful. Let us try and understand what happened in order to avoid repeating it.
Americans face hard choices: While it is important to alleviate the miserable conditions of the long-term unemployed today, we also need to offer them incentives and a pathway to building the skills that are required by the jobs that are being created. Simplistic mantras like "more stimulus" are the surest way to detract us from policies that generate sustainable growth.
Finally, a note on method. Perhaps Krugman believes that by labeling other economists as politically extreme, he can undercut their credibility. In criticizing my argument that politicians pushed easy housing credit in the years leading up to the crisis, he writes, "Although Rajan is careful not to name names and attributes the blame to generic ‘politicians,' it is clear that Democrats are largely to blame in his worldview." Yet if he read the book carefully, he would have seen that I do name names, arguing that both Bill Clinton with his "Affordable Housing Mandate" (p. 35) as well as George W. Bush with his attempt to foster an "Ownership Society" (p. 37) pushed very hard to expand housing credit to those who could not afford it. Indeed, I do not fault the intent of that policy, only the unintended consequences of its execution. Those consequence will be with us for years to come -- and perhaps longer if we learn the wrong lessons from this crisis.

Swedish rout highlights European socialist crisis

http://www.reuters.com/article/idUSTRE68J28520100920


(Reuters) - The crash of Sweden's long-ruling Social Democrats to their worst defeat since 1914 highlights the decline of socialist parties in much of Europe, drained by social change, economic crisis and the rise of new issues.
The re-election of a center-right Swedish government for the first time in modern history and the entry of a hard-right anti-immigrant party into parliament show how far the times have changed, even in social democracy's north European heartland.
How the center-left should respond, and whether it can regain the ascendancy in Europe at a time when loyalties are shifting across the political spectrum, are now being fought out in internal party tussles in Britain and France in particular.
In Sweden as in Germany, France, Denmark or the Netherlands, the main party of the center-left has hemorrhaged votes in all directions -- to the hard left, the ecologist Greens, the populist far right but also to mainstream conservatives.
"Social democracy comes across as a victim of the crisis, when it should appear as a refuge or a hope after years of neo-liberal excess," French political scientist Laurent Bouvet wrote earlier this year.
Technological change and globalization have shrunk the traditional industrial working class and the trade unions, made jobs more precarious and thrown up new issues such as climate change, population aging, immigration, obesity and drugs.
The mainstream left is torn between trying to reconnect with a lost popular electorate and reaching out to an aspiring new class in the knowledge economy.
Swedish Social Democratic leader Mona Sahlin alienated some centrist supporters by agreeing to a formal coalition with the ex-communist Left party -- a move that the German Social Democratic Party (SPD) continues to eschew.
ACCOMPLICE?
In countries such as Britain, France and Germany, where the center-left was in government in the early 2000s, it is regarded by many voters as having been a zealous accomplice in financial deregulation and economic liberalism.
Rising income inequality gave a hollow ring to the left's proclaimed ambition to redistribute wealth.
Now that most European countries are burdened with high deficits and debt mountains due to the financial crisis, the "big government" left is not seen as offering a credible answer to the question of where and how to shrink the state.
In many countries, public employees are the biggest bloc of socialist party members and constitute a brake on reform.
Socialists' long-standing support for European unification, religious tolerance and integrating immigrants has made them vulnerable to right-wing populists like the Sweden Democrats, Geert Wilders' Dutch Freedom Party or France's National Front.
These dilemmas are the backdrop to the choice of a new leader by Britain's opposition Labor Party this week, and of a presidential candidate by the French Socialist party next year.
In Britain, the choice is between sticking to the market-friendly New Labor ideology that marked Tony Blair's decade in office from 1997, or shifting to the left to try to win back disenchanted working class and public sector voters.
"We need to become 'effective state' social democrats, not 'big state' social democrats," Roger Liddle, one of the thinkers behind the New Labor project, said in a speech last week.
Former foreign secretary David Miliband embodies Blairite continuity, while his younger brother Ed, former cabinet minister Ed Balls and left-wing stalwart Diane Abbott offer varying degrees of the latter approach.
GREENS RISING
In France, the Socialists face a potential three-way choice between a social-liberal (International Monetary Fund chief Dominique Strauss-Kahn), an old-style socialist (current party leader Martine Aubry), and a left-populist (defeated 2007 presidential candidate Segolene Royal).
Aubry and Royal have vowed to reverse President Nicolas Sarkozy's pension reform, which pushes back the retirement age from 60 to 62 and makes many work until 67 for a full pension. Strauss-Kahn says retirement at 60 cannot be a "dogma" when people are living ever longer.
An ecologist list ran neck-and-neck with the French Socialist party in last year's European Parliament elections, siphoning off so-called Bobo voters (the bohemian bourgeois), while ex-communists and Trotskyists split another 10 percent.
In Germany, the Greens are snapping at the heels of the opposition SPD in opinion polls and may get a chance to lead a regional state government for the first time next year.
But the SPD has also lost support to the hardline Left party among working class and elderly voters who felt betrayed by its reduction of unemployment benefits and extension of the retirement age while in government over the last decade.
Where socialists are still in office, in Spain, Portugal and Greece, they risk alienating their core electorate by having to implement austerity measures mandated by the IMF and the European Union in exchange for financial support.
Only Greek Prime Minister George Papandreou has managed to retain his lead in opinion polls so far despite eye-watering spending cuts -- perhaps because his conservative opponents made such a shambles of running public finances until last year.

More Than 250,000 British Toddlers Labeled Racists

http://www.foxnews.com/world/2010/09/23/british-toddlers-labeled-racists/?test=latestnews


More than a quarter million British children have been accused of racism since the country passed its Race Relations Act in 2000, the Daily Mail reports.
Munira Mirza, a senior adviser to London Mayor Boris Johnson, says teachers are being forced to report children as young as 3 years old to the authorities for using alleged "racist" language.
"Teachers are now required to report incidents of racist abuse among children as young as three to local authorities, resulting in a massive increase of cases and reinforcing the perception that we need an army of experts to manage race relations from cradle to grave," she wrote in Prospect magazine.
According to civil liberties group the Manifesto Club, 280,00 incidents have been reported between 2002-2009.

Prof calls fellow academics ‘sanctimonious bigots’

http://www.washingtonexaminer.com/opinion/blogs/beltway-confidential/prof-calls-fellow-academics-sanctimonious-bigots-103207814.html


By: Barbara Hollingsworth
Local Opinion Editor
09/18/10 4:35 PM EDT

If the Left acknowledged sin, hypocrisy would be one of the most unforgiveable. But that’s exactly what hundreds of university faculty members – many in women’s and gender studies departments – were found guilty of during a recent experiment devised by a University of Illinois economics professor.
Prof. Fred Gottheil told Front Page Magazine that he compiled a list of 675 email addresses from 900 signatures on a 2009 petition authored by Dr. David Lloyd, professor of English at the University of Southern California, urging the U.S. to abandon its ally, Israel. Prof. Gottheil discovered that six of the signers, who hailed from more than 150 college campuses, were members of his own faculty.

“Would these same 900 sign onto a statement expressing concern about human rights violations in the Muslim Middle East, such as honor killing, wife beating, female genital mutilation, and violence against gays and lesbians?” he wondered. “I felt it was worth a try.”

The results? “Almost non existent,” he told Front Page editor Jamie Glazov. Only 27 of the 675 “self-described social-justice seeking academics” agreed to sign Gottheil’s Statement of Concern – less than 5 percent of the total who had publicly called for the censure of Israel for human rights violations.
The refusal of women’s studies professors to publicly condemn honor killings, or academic advocates of gay rights to speak out against the treatment of homosexuals in Muslim countries, is just about as hypocritical as it gets. Their loathing (dare we call it hate?) of the UN-created Jewish state is so deep that it “trump[s] their professional interests,” leading them into a “ideologically discriminatory trap of their own making,” Prof. Gottheil added.

“The academic Left may be just a little more sophisticated [than the non-academic Left] in their loathing of Israel, but scratch the surface and it’s all the same…It turns out that with all their professing of principle, they are sanctimonious bigots at heart.”


Read more at the Washington Examiner: http://www.washingtonexaminer.com/opinion/blogs/beltway-confidential/prof-calls-fellow-academics-sanctimonious-bigots-103207814.html#ixzz10XVkrbAB

Friday, September 10, 2010

Government 2.0 Study Makes Case for "Change" in Government - Highlights Challenges...

http://www.reuters.com/article/idUS112751+22-Sep-2008+BW20080922


Mon Sep 22, 2008 8:00am EDT
Government 2.0 Study Makes Case for "Change" in Government - Highlights Challenges of Transition from Rhetoric to Reality

     Federal Managers and Average Americans Agree Poor Management
         Practices Squander at Least One-Third of Tax Dollars
CRYSTAL CITY, Va.--(Business Wire)--
Primavera Systems, Inc., today announced the results of its second
annual government management study - "Government 2.0 - The Performance
Opportunity." The study shows that both Federal managers and average
Americans are calling for management reform in the next
administration. Federal managers leverage their inside knowledge to
provide specific recommendations on how the next administration can
improve. These recommendations point to Government 2.0 - the next
generation of government that leverages technology to enable two-way
communication with the public, improve management practices, and
prepare the leaders of the future.

   Gaps in Perception - Cracks in Foundation

   With mere weeks until the next Presidential election, the study
reveals that average Americans believe that 42 percent of U.S. tax
dollars are wasted due to government inefficiency. The value of this
"Efficiency Gap" equates to the combined personal income tax payments
of approximately every taxpayer in the 11 states that comprise the
Northeast. Surprisingly, Federal managers echoed the perception of
waste, reporting that they believe nearly one-third of their own tax
dollars are wasted or misused.

   Not a Lost Cause - Improve Management Processes and Tools

   Average Americans and Federal managers also agree that the
government must manage government programs more efficiently. Just 10
percent of Americans are satisfied with Federal management practices,
and only 17 percent of Federal managers would give their agency an "A"
for management effectiveness. Eighty-seven percent of Federal managers
say some or all wasted tax dollars could be recovered through improved
management practices.

   Three-quarters of Americans desire increased visibility into
Federal spending and management performance. Forty-three percent of
Federal managers assert that non-standard management systems in
Federal agencies present a significant obstacle to achieving this
goal.

   The Transition Is Not a Cure-All - Communicate to Achieve Results

   Few Federal managers believe the transition to a new
administration will result in immediate improvements. In fact, 63
percent believe that government performance accountability and reform
will suffer during the transition to the next administration. Federal
managers also gave the next administration thoughts on how to succeed
during the transition. Their most-cited piece of advice? Listen to
seasoned government managers.

   Americans, too, want to see more communication from the
government. Seventy-five percent of Americans would like the
government to notify them when a program goes over budget, why it is
over budget, and what the agency will do to fix the problem. Sixty
percent of Americans say the government should publish information
about government spending online.

   Visions for the Future - Federal Managers Offer Government 2.0
Advice

   Federal managers offer several pieces of advice to the next
administration. When asked how the government can improve management
practices, Federal managers provided the following recommendations:

   --  65 percent suggest a standardized system for reporting and
        tracking project updates and changes

   --  55 percent recommend a standardized system for reporting
        project problems in real time

   --  47 percent say that providing project managers with access to
        the same project information at the same time would greatly
        benefit management continuity across the board

   "Both average Americans and Federal managers are clearly focused
on the challenges and opportunities presented by the administration
transition," said Nicole Styer, Vice President, Marketing, Primavera.
"Echoing the presidential candidates' call for reform, accountability,
and transparency, this study outlines what needs to change if the
change talk is to go beyond rhetoric. Without enhanced and
standardized management infrastructure, no matter who wins in
November, Americans will be served up more of the same."

   Methodology

   The "Government 2.0 - The Performance Opportunity" findings are
based on an online survey of 3,868 members of the general public and
382 Federal managers. The general public survey has a margin of error
of +/-1.58 percent with a confidence level of 95 percent. The Federal
manager survey has a margin of error of +/-5.01 percent with a
confidence level of 95 percent. The study is available for download at
http://www.primavera.com/connect.

   About Primavera

   Primavera is the world's leading provider of project, resource and
portfolio management software. Our industry-specific solutions help
project-driven organizations create a competitive advantage by making
better portfolio investment decisions, improving governance,
prioritizing project investments and resources, and delivering
tangible results back to the business.

   Projects totaling more than $6 trillion in value have been managed
with Primavera by more than 75,000 customers around the world. Our
employees, global partners, award-winning customer support and
professional services teams are deeply committed to helping
organizations achieve their vision and strategy.

   We encourage you to learn how Primavera can help you meet your
project goals and business objectives. For greater detail on Primavera
solutions and real-world customer successes, visit www.primavera.com
today.

   Primavera and the Primavera sundial logo are trademarks of
Primavera Technologies, Inc. All other trademarks and service marks
mentioned herein are the property of their respective owners.

Primavera Systems, Inc.
Valerie Samansky, 610-949-6671
vsamansky@primavera.com
or
O'Keeffe & Company
Adrienne Reitz, 703-883-9000 ext. 131
areitz@okco.com

The Inherent Inefficiency Of Government Bureaucracy

http://www.ilw.com/articles/2010,0421-brownfeld.shtm


by Allan C. Brownfeld for the Foundation For Economic Education

There are few who will disagree with the fact that, in recent years, the governmental bureaucracy has grown dramatically while its effi ciency has deteriorated in an equal ly dramatic manner.
The data is instructive with regard to this state of affairs. In the twenty years between 1952 and 1972 the nondefense government payroll jumped 117 per cent. At the present time, there is one govern ment employee in domestic services for every 5.5 workers in private employment, with a ratio of 1:9.3 twenty years ago. More individuals were added to government service in these twenty years than in the preceding 163 years since the founding of the United States.
From 1952 to 1972, the cost of the public payroll multiplied more than fourfold, from $35 billion to $150 billion. The 330 per cent increase over that period exceeds the 247 per cent growth of employee compensa tion in private industries ($161 billion to $557 billion). In 1952, the average worker in private employ ment earned 5 per cent more than his counterpart in government. By 1972, he had fallen 10 per cent behind.1
The growth of the government bureaucracy has been accompanied by a decrease in its rate of efficien cy. Consider several examples.
Employment in the Department of Agriculture went up 47 per cent between 1952 and 1972 (78,000 to 115,000) although the number of farms in the U.S. dropped by 45 per cent (from 5.2 million to 2.9 million) and the farm population shrank 56 per cent (from 21.7 million to 9.6 million). More significantly, the cost of stabilization of farm prices and incomes multiplied seven times in this twenty-year period—from $689 million to $4,243 million.
In the Internal Revenue Service, the staff grew 28 per cent between 1952 and 1972 (56,336 to 72,085), almost parallel to the number of tax returns filed, which increased 26 per cent, from 89 million to 112 million. Yet, the number of tax returns per employee dropped from 1580 to 1554, even though during this same period the I.R.S. underwent its most intensive computerization and mechanization. At the same time, audits declined from 4.4 million to 1.7 million and delinquent notices from 19.8 million to 8.8 million.
Trends in Public Education
In the field of public education, enrollment almost doubled between 1952 and 1972 while the number of teachers and other school employees tripled. In 1952, there was one employee for every 14.8 students, while in 1972 there was one for every 9.2. Comparing the trends in public education and in other areas, Professor Roger Freeman notes that, "Trends in public education and in the American economy generally have been running in opposite directions. While throughout most of industry and agriculture, employee produc tivity, that is, the ratio between manpower input and product out put, has increased consistently and substantially, it has just as con­sistently and sharply declined in public education."
The fact is that there seems to be a decline in American educational standards just as the expenditure of money and the number of person nel have dramatically increased. Results of scholastic aptitude test scores show a decline in almost every knowledge and skill area.
In yet another area of public employment, police protection, we find precisely the same trend. Dur ing the 1952-1972 period there was an increase of 129 per cent in the number of employees while the U.S. population expanded only 33 per cent. There were 1.6 police employees per 1,000 population in 1952 and 2.8 in 1972. Despite this increased ratio of protection, crime did not decrease—it increased. Between 1957 and 1972, the U.S. population grew 22 per cent, the number of police employees in­creased 84 per cent—nearly four times faster—while the estimated number of crimes jumped 309 per cent, from 1.4 million to 5.9 million.
These examples are, of course, on ly skimming the surface of the available material. A look at the regulatory agencies—the Civil Aeronautics Board, the Interstate Commerce Commission, the Food and Drug Administration, and the like—will bring us to the same con clusion. So will a look at the U.S. Postal Service and, unfortunately, at almost every other U.S. govern mental agency—including the Department of Defense.
Reasons for Inefficiency
There are some who look at this data, which is difficult to dispute in itself, and argue that the bureau cracy needs to be reorganized, supervised in a better manner, be made more responsive to the peo ple, and so on. The proposition they seem to accept is that bureaucracy is not necessarily inefficient and uneconomical in itself, but can be corrected. The more legitimate con clusion to be drawn from the data, however, is that it is governmental bureaucracy which is inherently inefficient—and for a number of very good reasons.
That we are faced with gross inef ficiency is clear. In a review of re cent academic studies of govern ment bureaucracy in The Public Ad ministration Review (March-April, 1974), Kenneth F. Warren con cludes: "The authors’ consensus, with Mainzer dissenting, is that American bureaucracy is guilty of gross mismanagement of the public interest. The real accountability crisis is that even if our bureaucrats act inefficiently and against our in terests, as is too often the case, we cannot realistically hope for ad ministrative abuses to be checked by the present ‘watchdog’ system."
Similarly, in the book, Democracy and the Public Service, Frederick C. Mosher found that professionalism in governmental bureaucracy and the power of the civil service pose a distinct threat to democratic con trol; that is, they are self-serving rather than serving the public in terest. In another study, Richard S. Rosenbloom, in the Harvard Business Review (September-October, 1973), noted that, "The largest employee group in the U.S. has shown the least concern for worker productivity. This seems ab­surd in a society that prides itself on management and efficiency, but the fact appears to be indisput able. . . . Not only is productivity in these groups lagging, but little is being done about it . . . One is less surprised at the absence of evident productivity growth in government when it is recognized that none of the major forces operating in the private sector applies in govern ment."
The fact which must be remem bered is that inefficiency is by no means an accident in public enter prise but is built into such non competitive endeavor. In his impor tant book,The Growth Of American Government, Dr. Roger Freeman makes this point: "We must recognize that, in contrast to private industry, where competition and the profit motive impose pressure for greater efficiency and a natural and generally reliable gauge of productivity, governmental pro grams have built-in counterproductive trends. It is a natural tendency for a public employee to want to handle fewer cases—pupils, tax returns, welfare families, crimes—in the belief that he could do a better job if he had a smaller workload, and most certainly have an easier life. For the supervisor there is a definite gain in stature, position—and even grade—by having a larger number of subordinates. This and the ideological commitments to the program goals and methods of their professional fraternities provide a powerful and well-nigh irresistible incentive for empire building."
The Direct Beneficiaries
Government programs are so structured that the incentive is never to solve whatever problem is being dealt with—but to see to it that it is exacerbated, and that more money becomes necessary to fight it. In the so-called "War On Poverty," for example, programs were not designed to give money to the poor, whatever the merits of that would have been, but, instead, to give money to people who were to provide "services" to the poor.
The result has been that the only poverty such legislation corrected was that of its own employees.
Today, many thousands of well-organized individuals and groups have a vested interest in the con tinuation of many otherwise useless and costly programs. This is the "Education-Poverty-Social Work er" complex discussed by many who do care about the poor.
The cost of Medicaid, which is on ly one of many such costly pro grams, is now approaching $15 billion annually, more than triple the cost in 1970. The beneficiaries, largely, are not the poor, but the ever-growing number of profes sionals who receive the money. The incentive is to spend as much as possible, not as little. The poor are simply pawns in someone else’s game. The same is true of urban renewal, job training, and a host of other bureaucratic programs. The poor are not helped—and are often harmed—while the building con tractors and "job trainers" get rich with public funds. "Poverty," as Barron’s correspondent Shirley Scheibla has said, "is where the money is."
Child Care
The same is true with Federally sponsored child development and day care centers. The motivation for such programs is not the idea that the poor need help. It is, instead, the notion that the govern ment is better equipped to take care of children than are their parents—a presumption which flies in the face of most medical evidence.
Dr. John Bowlby, a distinguished British physician, has done exten sive study on the effect of material deprivation, entitled "Maternal Care and Mental Health." His conclusion: "It is plain that, when deprived of maternal care, the child’s development is almost always retarded—physically, in tellectually, and socially—and that symptoms of physical and mental ill ness may appear." This conclusion is corroborated by Dr. Jack Raskin, director of the Seattle Children’s Orthopedic Hospital Psychiatry Service: "There is no good substi tute for the mother’s presence. The best day care center in the world cannot begin to compete in this regard with the average mother."
Whether we turn to medical care, housing, jobs or day care, the presumption of those who urge ex pensive government programs is always that government is best equipped to efficiently deal with the problem. In fact, the idea of social programs to help people to help themselves has itself come to an end. Now, we seem content to place whole classes of people upon welfare or some other form of public sup port, with little concern about their long-run well-being or the well being of society as a whole. Un fortunately, a class of people—government bureaucrats and those hired by government—profits from such a system. Professor Aaron Wildaysky summarized the situa tion: "Middle class civil servants hired upper class student radicals to use lower class Negroes as a bat tering ram against the existing local political system." In his book, In Our Time, Eric Hoffer points out that, "Those in charge were less in terested in healing and conciliating the weak than in aggravating their illness and sharpening their grievances. Thus, by a perverted dialectic, our wholehearted effort to right wrongs was shown to be proof not of our concern for righteousness but of our present and past in curable wrongness."
A War to Lose
Unfortunately, those who in stituted the War on Poverty had a vested interest in losing it. If pover ty were ever to come to an end, so would their jobs. The incentives in almost all such government pro grams are negative—for, if they were positive, those carrying out the work would find themselves, before too long, unemployed. That is why, as was indicated earlier, the number of employees at the Depart ment of Agriculture increases each year—while the number of farmers declines.
We have thus come to the point where the real constituency of government’s expensive social pro grams are the bureaucrats themselves. Former Senator James Buckley notes that, "We must count not just the numbers of in tended beneficiaries, but the enor mous influence and wealth of the in terests that are their indirect beneficiaries—interests that can play an extraordinarily persuasive role in defining the areas of ‘com passion’ they are called upon to ser vice."
Ludwig von Mises on the Nature of Bureaucracy
The evidence is persuasive that government bureaucracy is in herently inefficient precisely because it is not faced with any of the forces which make private business management its opposite. This point has been made frequent ly. In his book, Bureaucracy, Lud wig von Mises goes to some length to explain it. He declared that, "It is a widespread illusion that the effi ciency of government bureaus could be improved by management engineers and their methods of scientific management. . . . What they call deficiencies and faults of the management of administrative agencies are necessary properties. A bureau is not a profit-seeking enterprise; it cannot make use of any economic calculation. . . . It is out of the question to improve its management by reshaping it ac cording to the pattern of private business."
To those well-meaning but ill-informed observers of bureaucratic inefficiency, Von Mises addressed this message: "No reform can remove the bureaucratic features of the government’s bureaus. It is useless to blame them for their slowness and slackness. It is vain to lament over the fact that the assiduity, carefulness, and painstaking work of the average bureau clerk are, as a rule, below those of the average worker in private business . . . In the absence of an unquestionable yardstick of success and failure it is almost im possible for the vast majority of men to find that incentive to ut most exertion that the money calculus of profit-seeking business easily provides. . . . All such defi ciencies are inherent in the per formance of services which cannot be checked by money statements of profit and loss."
The Reorganization Snare
It is high time that those speak ing of governmental "reorganiza tion" understand that this is not, in the long run, the proper manner in which to approach the question of an ever-increasing and increasingly expensive and inefficient govern mental bureaucracy. In an impor tant article, Rowland Egger, writ ing for the National Tax Association, discussed the whole notion of "administrative reorganization." He provided this assessment: "The attempt to sell administrative reor ganization legislation on the basis of tax reduction, however honorable the motives and however laudable the hopes of those who support ad ministrative reorganization for this reason, is a snare and a delu sion. . . . Administrative reorgan ization never saved large sums of money. . . . The plain fact is that the only way to save significant sums of money in the federal establish ment is to eliminate activities and reduce the scale of operations. . . . There is no royal road, no painless way, to government economy."
A projection of governmental employment trends to the year 2000 would show that government employees totaled 16.2 million in 1972 and had increased 124 per cent in nondefense positions in the preceding twenty years. If these trends were to continue for the balance of the century, defense employment would fall an addi tional 1.3 million to 2.2 million, while all other governmental employment would triple from 12.7 million to 39 million for an ag gregate of 41 million in the year 2000. The entire labor force has been projected to rise from 89 million in 1972 to 112.6 million in 1990. It could reach or exceed 120 million by the year 2000. Assuming that 94 per cent of the labor force were then employed, there would be 113 million jobholders of whom, ac cording to these projections, 41 million, or 36 per cent, would be in government.
The Trends Projected: All Government!
Professor C. Northcote Parkinson in 1958 calculated that if the trend in Britain’s public employment were to continue at the prevailing rate, everyone in Britain would be working for the government by the year 2195. In 1971, New York’s Morgan Guaranty Trust Company applied the same idea to the U.S. and found that if things continued at the present rate, every American would be on the public payroll by 2049—a century and a half sooner than in Britain.
The illusion that bureaucratic in efficiency can be corrected should come to a rapid end. Such inefficien cy is inherent in public enterprise. Once this premise is accepted, it will rapidly be seen that the only form of government reorganization which will be effective is to reduce government itself. Whatever the reformers of bureaucracy may tell us, the inefficiency of the bureaucrats is no accident.
This article was originally published by the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE) in The Freeman on June 1977 • Volume: 27 • Issue: 6.

End Notes
1These and other statistics that follow are from The Growth of American Government by Roger A. Freeman (Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press, 1975).